05.08.2024 - Comments

Central Banks: Data and Narrative Dependent

by Pablo Duarte


Central banks actively pursue an inflation target, primarily via interest rate policy. They discarded their previous inflation models after failing to predict the post-pandemic surge in inflation. Now, they claim to be “data-dependent,” yet their data selection remains rooted in the old “output gap” model. Market participants, aware of the importance of interest rate policy, closely monitor the same data central banks use to make decisions. They overlook, however, the development of the money supply, which offers relevant signals for inflation trends. Investors with a longer time horizon could benefit by focusing on the true drivers of inflation rather than on the data central banks prioritize.

Data-dependent central banks: what data?

Macroeconomic models commonly used to explain inflation rely on the Phillips curve, according to which there is a negative relationship between inflation and the production potential of an economy. Potential output estimates the level of production achievable if labor and capital operate at full capacity. When production exceeds this potential, labor and capital are strained, leading to rising prices as supply struggles to meet demand.

These models assume that central banks can control the economy. When inflation arises, the central bank is expected to raise policy rates to make borrowing more expensive, thereby “cooling demand” and reducing capacity utilization, which should, in theory, bring inflation down.

However, the empirical evidence supporting this narrative is weak. For years, academics have debated why the Phillips curve have flattened or who has killed it.1 Because central banks nevertheless used this model as a guide, they incorrectly interpreted the rise in inflation in 2021 as temporary.

Although the central banks have since discarded this model for interest rate policy making and, according to their own statements, are “data dependent”, they still follow the old approach conceptually. They look for signals of “overheating” or “cooling” of the economy from indicators of the real economy.

However, it’s doubtful that an interest rate policy based on these signals can effectively control inflation. While purchasing managers' indices (PMIs) are seen as reliable economic indicators and summarize the data central banks monitor, the correlation between PMI and core PCE inflation—the Fed's target—in the United States is statistically insignificant (Figure 1). This holds true for both simultaneous and lagged relationships between the variables.

If purchasing managers' indices do indeed provide a good and timely summary of economic development and capacity utilization, it means that central banks are relying on data that are not very relevant for understanding inflation. Nevertheless, many market participants follow this approach because central bank decisions are more important to them than the actual development of inflation.

What are the markets looking at?

Robert Armstrong and his team regularly discuss the mood and concerns of financial market participants in the Financial Times column “Unhedged.” It’s evident from their discussions that market participants closely monitor actual data and leading economic indicators.2

A study by the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) shows that PMIs and financial market variables are indeed highly correlated.3 Financial market variables also react to surprises in the PMI data.4 In recent years, PMI readings that were higher than the median of a Bloomberg survey have been accompanied by slight reductions in yields on 2-year US government bonds (Fig. 2, correlation coefficient -0.24).

If the relationship between growth and inflation does not correspond to the output gap model, then central banks are on the wrong track. Market participants follow them because to many the interest rate policy decisions are more important than what they achieve.

What should we focus on?

Inflation can arise through several channels, all of which should be considered (Mayer, 2024). In a recent commentary in the Journal of Monetary Economics, US economist Gregory Mankiw (2024) recommended a stronger focus on the money supply. His argument is simple: those who accurately predicted inflation did so by correctly assessing the development of the money supply.

The fact that there is a relationship between money supply and the price level is nothing new. The quantity theory of money (M * v = P * Y), which originated in the 16th century, states that nominal income over a given period must correspond with a certain money flow.5 This money flow (M * v) consists of the money supply (M) and the frequency with which money changes hands, known as the velocity of money (v). Income (P * Y) is composed of real income (Y) and the price level (P). Originally, this relationship was defined as an identity. However, the velocity of money (v) tends to change slowly over time, while production (Y) is determined by real economic factors. Therefore, the development of the money supply should at least temporarily influence the price level.

Mayer (2022) defines a money overhang as “an expansion of the money supply (M) that is not compensated for by a corresponding fundamental increase in the demand for money (permanent decline in v).” A money overhang must therefore be reflected in a higher nominal income. Since real income is not primarily dependent on the money supply, but on productivity growth, a money overhang is likely to be accompanied by an increase in the price level.

Given that both the money supply and nominal income in the U.S. are trending upward, it is useful to examine deviations from this trend. Unlike with PMIs, the correlation between deviations in the M2 money supply from the 10-year average and the (annual) core PCE inflation one year later is positive and statistically significant, both before and after the pandemic (Fig. 3). This relationship has proven to be robust over time.

Between 2009 and 2019, the gap between the money supply and its 10-year average ranged from 30 to 35% (Fig. 4). With the expansive monetary measures implemented to combat the pandemic, this gap increased to 55% and remained at that level for several months. Core inflation rose to over 5% twelve months later and stayed at that level as well. The decline in our money surplus indicator coincides with a subsequent decrease in inflation. If this correlation persists over the next twelve months, it could suggest that the money surplus has diminished, meaning prices may no longer rise as sharply. Consequently, inflation would likely return to pre-pandemic levels.

 

However, this forecast comes with some uncertainties. First, a change in the velocity of money due to a structural shift in money demand could alter the correlation, causing the gap from the trend associated with 2% inflation and real U.S. growth to be higher or lower. Potential reasons for this include higher energy prices due to geopolitical tensions or increased wages driven by labor shortages. Second, a recession could trigger an expansionary monetary policy, potentially creating a new money overhang. However, if the current trend in the money supply remains relevant, a moderate decline in core inflation in the US over the next twelve months seems likely.

Conclusion

Although central banks emphasize that they are “data-dependent”, their selection of indicators shows that they continue to follow models that focus on the real economy. However, the development of the money supply provides other important indications of inflation developments. Short-term investors will likely continue to follow the central banks' perspective, as interest rate movements are crucial for them, even if monetary policy misses the mark on inflation. However, longer-term investors should keep an eye on the development of the money supply, as it significantly impacts inflation and could force central banks to adjust their interest rate policies.


1 See, for example, Del Negro et al. (2020), Ratner & Sim (2022), Stock & Watson (2020).

2 See Falling inflation, sturdy economy, happy Fed (ft.com).

3 See Erik et al. (2019).

4 See Datta et al. (2021).

5 See Mayer (2022).


References

Datta, D. D., Johannsen, B. K., Kwon, H., & Vigfusson, R. J. (2021). Oil, equities, and the zero lower bound. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 13(2), 214-253.

Del Negro, M., Lenza, M., Primiceri, G.E., & Tambalotti, A. (2020). What's up with the Phillips Curve? (No. w27003). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Erik, B., Lombardi, M.J., Mihaljek, D., & Shin, H.S. (2019). Financial conditions and purchasing managers' indices: exploring the links. BIS Quarterly Review, September.

Ratner, David, and Jae Sim (2022). "Who Killed the Phillips Curve? A Murder Mystery," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2022-028. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve Systemhttps://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2022.028

Mankiw, N. G. (2024). Six Beliefs I Have About Inflation: Remarks Prepared for NBER Conference on “Inflation in the Covid Era”. Journal of Monetary Economics, 103631.

Mayer, Thomas (2022), The "monetary phenomenon", Flossbach von Storch Research Institute, Study.

Mayer, Thomas (2024), A Latticework of Inflation Models. Flossbach von Storch Research Institute, Study.

Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (2020). Slack and cyclically sensitive inflation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 52(S2), 393-428.

Legal notice

The information contained and opinions expressed in this document reflect the views of the author at the time of publication and are subject to change without prior notice. Forward-looking statements reflect the judgement and future expectations of the author. The opinions and expectations found in this document may differ from estimations found in other documents of Flossbach von Storch AG. The above information is provided for informational purposes only and without any obligation, whether contractual or otherwise. This document does not constitute an offer to sell, purchase or subscribe to securities or other assets. The information and estimates contained herein do not constitute investment advice or any other form of recommendation. All information has been compiled with care. However, no guarantee is given as to the accuracy and completeness of information and no liability is accepted. Past performance is not a reliable indicator of future performance. All authorial rights and other rights, titles and claims (including copyrights, brands, patents, intellectual property rights and other rights) to, for and from all the information in this publication are subject, without restriction, to the applicable provisions and property rights of the registered owners. You do not acquire any rights to the contents. Copyright for contents created and published by Flossbach von Storch AG remains solely with Flossbach von Storch AG. Such content may not be reproduced or used in full or in part without the written approval of Flossbach von Storch AG.

Reprinting or making the content publicly available – in particular by including it in third-party websites – together with reproduction on data storage devices of any kind requires the prior written consent of Flossbach von Storch AG.

© 2024 Flossbach von Storch. All rights reserved.